Monthly Archives: August 2013

Herding, Crowding and “Heterogeneous Motivations” (oh my!)

Consider this quote from a local investment professional in Malaysia:

When foreigners sell, that’s the best time to buy. [Foreigners] buy only when the market is going up, and they push the price way up. And they sell all the way down. They do all the wrong things. They are willing to sell all the way down to owning nothing in the Malaysian stock market.

And this one:

Fund managers in foreign houses are exposed to a lot of things. They don’t look at one angle, they look at several angles. Same topic, but they look at different angles. If you can look at a certain situation in a different way, you will win points. So it’s good to talk with foreign funds. Most of them have been longer in the industry than most [Malaysians]. And they are exposed to analysts from different countries, and these analysts have different ways of looking at things.

Which one is right?

Aaron Pitluck, a sociologist, looks at why traders invest in emerging markets, and asks why locals either seem to replicate the foreign traders’ trades, or trade against them.  One explanation is that locals perceive foreigners to be less knowledgable or less skilled (and therefore the locals try to trade against them); another is that locals view foreigners as being at least as well-informed, or better-informed, than locals, causing the locals to imitate the foreign investors.  But which is the more persuasive explanation?

Pitluck suggests a different explanation altogether:  neither is correct. Instead, he posits that local and foreign participants are playing different games and that the games can’t be compared directly.  And this, he suggests, can be good for liquidity:

[O]ne significant contribution to a market’s liquidity may be a market with heterogeneous participants with respect to strategic intentions for trading. Additionally, markets may be more liquid when participants have heterogeneous information sets (i.e., having heterogeneous views of what information is salient and heterogeneous interpretations of public information). Conversely, one cause of illiquidity may be when market participants’ strategic intention sets or information sets become more homogenous, and/or when traders with heterogeneous strategy or information sets increasingly avoid trading.

In other words, although they are usually buying and selling the same securities, local and foreign participants may be guided by divergent motivations that make them willing to trade against each other even though they all have the same information.  Foreign exchange rate fluctuations, for example, may induce foreign investors to sell because it reduces their IRR, even as local investors see a buy opportunity because the new exchange rate promises a favorable benefit to a local listed company.  Or the foreign investor may be liquidating a position in one country to take advantage of an opportunity in another, while local participants are limited by regulation or resources to stay in the local market.  In either case, their strategies are incommensurable; they can’t be described as either “following the herd” or “separating the fools from their money.”  They’re just playing different games.

The point here is that regulations and policies that encourage participation by players with heterogeneous motivations may promote liquidity, because it increases the likelihood that rational participants will meet as counterparties.  Market operators and apex regulators looking to improve liquidity in a local market should therefore consider steps they can take to create the conditions for heterogeneous motivations, whether through loosening barriers to foreign direct investment, or promoting local regulations that will shift the motivations of local participants.

Transparency, Accountability and Participation

Recently, the Open Government Partnership posted an open letter to UN Secretary General Ban Ki Moon regarding Open Government and the post-2015 Development Framework.  The letter applauds the report of the UN’s High Level Panel of Eminent Persons (HLPEP) on the Post 2015 Development Agenda, and strongly encourages the Secretary General and the UN to stress transparency, participation and accountability in the next round of global development goals.

While the OGP letter was aimed at policy making well beyond the financial markets, the point that their letter stresses applies equally well to policy makers at an apex financial regulator, and to market operators.  The existence of Big Data, and the ease with which it can be analyzed and understood has changed the calculus between service providers and end users.  End users expect to be able to see and understand what goes on beneath the surface, and to evaluate for themselves the risks and benefits of participation.  They also expect the provider to be accountable for its actions.

What does this mean to a market operator?  It means that in order to attract market participants, the operator must be comfortable with transparency – that is, the operator should offer clear rules and guidance in how the market works; have clear processes for changing the rules of the game; and give participants tools with which to evaluate the market for efficiency and efficacy.  It also means that operators must be responsive to participants.  After all, especially in an emerging market, participants are volunteers – they don’t need to come into your marketplace at all.  If you want them to, you need to make sure they understand what they’re getting into, and that you’ll treat them fairly if they do come.

The same is true for apex regulators.  Regulators must be the policeman on the beat, to be sure, but they are also providing a service – an orderly and predictable market based on honesty and fair play; rules and rulemaking processes that are easy to understand and follow; and a commitment to nurturing new ideas or products proposed by a market operator or participant rather than just reflexively saying “no.” Being a service provider  – in other words, being customer focused – without being too pliant is a difficult balance for a regulator to pull off.  But a regulator who can be transparent, and holds itself accountable to its various constituents, will have credibility when it needs to make the unpopular decisions.  These will, over the long haul, lead to increased participation.

And that’s good for everybody.

Quote

Staffing Advice: “Unite public zeal with unusual capacity”

Nothing less is involved than to keep Wall Street in its place, to furnish a counterpoise against its aggrandisement of power, by which the Street all along the line resists efforts by the government for the common interest. And so plainly, you need administrators who are equipped to meet the best legal brains whom Wall Street always has at its disposal, who have stamina and do not weary of the fight, who are moved neither by blandishments nor fears, who in a word, unite public zeal with unusual capacity.

Advice from Felix Frankfurter to President Franklin Roosevelt on staffing the newly-formed SEC, in a letter dated May 23, 1934, but also sound strategic advice to apex regulators today.